Paying to Match: Decentralized Markets with
Information Frictions
*
Marina Agranov
Ahrash Dianat
Larry Samuelson
§
Leeat Yariv
January 24, 2023
Abstract
We experimentally study decentralized one-to-one matching markets with transfers. We vary the informa-
tion available to participants, complete or incomplete, and the surplus structure, supermodular or submod-
ular. Several insights emerge. First, while markets often culminate in ecient matchings, stability is more
elusive, reflecting the diculty of arranging attendant transfers. Second, incomplete information and sub-
modularity present hurdles to eciency and especially stability; their combination drastically diminishes
stability’s likelihood. Third, matchings form “from the top down in complete-information supermodular
markets, but exhibit many more and less-obviously ordered oers otherwise. Last, participants’ market
positions matter far more than their dynamic bargaining styles for outcomes.
Keywords: Matching Markets, Transfers, Incomplete Information, Experiments.
JEL: C78, C92, D02, D47.
*
We thank Jeongbin Kim and Pellumb Reshidi for superb research assistance. We gratefully acknowledge financial
support from the International Foundation for Research in Experimental Economics and from the NSF, through grant
SES 1629613.
Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences, California Institute of Technology, Email: [email protected]
Department of Economics, University of Essex, Email: [email protected]
§
Department of Economics, Yale University, Email: [email protected]
Department of Economics, Princeton University, Email: [email protected]
1 Introduction
1.1 Overview
A large and successful literature studies matching markets with complete information. It as-
sumes individuals know not only their own preferences over possible allocations, but also all
others’ preferences. This assumption is often made for tractability and is reasonable for some
applications. In large school choice systems, for example, historical data on admission patterns
might be persistent and therefore predictable. Nevertheless, there are numerous applications in
which incomplete information regarding others’ preferences, at times even ones own, might be
present. Newly-minted doctors seeking a residency in a specific specialty may not be privy to
the idiosyncratic preferences of both their peers and the hospitals they interview with. Similarly,
fresh academic Ph.D.s may not be fully informed of other applicants’ preferences or of universi-
ties’ particular research and teaching needs. Outside the labor market, potential adoptive parents
are unlikely to know the preferences over child characteristics of other potential adoptive parents
seeking children, or of the birth mothers relinquishing them. In marriage markets, an entire con-
sulting industry builds on the premise that individuals frequently misread others’ preferences,
even after lengthy interactions. While incomplete information is prevalent across these applica-
tions, there is a paucity of empirical data to elucidate its impacts.
We report results from an array of lab experiments in which participants match through de-
centralized interactions, as in the examples above. Our treatments vary the surplus structure and
the initial information available to market participants about others’ preferences. We illustrate
the substantial eect limited information has on outcomes and the regularities it produces.
Since many markets operate through transfers—labor markets often entail targeted wages,
housing markets generate exchanges via prices, etc.—we consider decentralized matching mar-
kets allowing for transfers. While common wisdom suggests that transfers assist in equilibrating
economic systems, they also allow for various bargaining frictions to emerge when negotiations
are unconstrained. Dierences in bargaining styles, failures to follow up with appropriate oers,
and the like could, in principle, aect the generated match surpluses and their split between par-
ties. Furthermore, in practice, implementing the “right” transfers might be challenging: agents
often interact with a small set of potential partners and have limited information on what others
1
should reasonably expect to receive. The challenge of finding the “right” transfers is compounded
by agents’ incomplete information about others’ preferences. Our design allows us to discern how
transfers evolve and get determined.
Experimental Design. While our study speaks to many applications, field data are dicult to
gather. Rarely do we know market participants’ true preferences, their detailed interactions, or
the information available to them. The lab setting allows us to control for dierent market features
and observe how individuals respond.
We consider two-sided one-to-one markets in which agents can make match oers to one an-
other. Agents in the market are characterized by their “types,” which can stand for education level
or expertise in labor markets, age in child-adoption processes, or pizzazz in the marriage setting.
All agents prefer to be matched with higher-type agents: they generate a greater match surplus.
Going back to Becker (1973), the matching literature has often assumed match surpluses
exhibit either supermodularity or submodularity; see Chade, Eeckhout, and Smith (2017) and
Chiappori (2017) for literature surveys. We accordingly consider two surplus structures: super-
modular and submodular. In supermodular markets, higher types experience a greater marginal
increase in generated surplus from matching with higher types. Consequently, the utilitarian
ecient matching is positively assortative. In submodular markets, the reverse holds: it is the
lower-type agents who experience the greatest marginal benefit from increasing their partner’s
quality. In such markets, utilitarian eciency implies negatively assortative matchings.
In our experimental markets, interactions are decentralized: individuals can make oers to
one another in an unscripted fashion, with the sole restriction that only one oer can be made or
accepted at any time. An oer indicates a split of the match surplus. Accepted oers generate ten-
tative matches—they can be broken by making a dierent oer that gets accepted, or by accepting
an alternative oer. A market terminates after 30 seconds of inactivity. We use this matching pro-
tocol for three reasons. First, it echoes the narrative underlying the cooperative underpinnings of
stable matchings with complete information: any coalition can be formed throughout a market’s
duration. Second, it provides participants ample opportunities to learn about others’ match qual-
ities, which is important for some of our analysis. Last, it captures features of many real-world
matching settings, where pairs negotiate with a variety of partners before settling on a permanent
match. For example, employees can negotiate with one firm and switch to negotiations with an-
2
other, home buyers inspecting a property can decide to forgo that property and inspect others,
and individuals seeking a life partner often date multiple individuals sequentially.
1
In our complete-information treatments, participants know the surplus generated by each pair
of participants in the market. In our incomplete-information treatments, participants enter the
market knowing the profile of match surpluses they can generate. That is, they know their own
type. They do not, however, know the types of other participants. In particular, at the start of the
market, they do not know who will help them generate which surplus. Learning occurs through
market interactions. Whenever an oer is accepted, both partners learn the match surplus they
jointly generate and the resulting payos they receive.
2
The full market observes the creation of
matches, as well as the surplus that recipients of accepted oers receive, but not the total surplus
such matches generate.
Empirical Regularities. Several insights emerge from our analysis. As we describe in our liter-
ature review below, prior experimental work supports the impression that, at least without trans-
fers, decentralized interaction yields stable outcomes. Our results show that matching markets
with transfers often produce utilitarian ecient matchings, but stable outcomes are less com-
mon.
3
Thus, there is a sense in which the common wisdom on the benefits of transfers holds
water in our data, albeit at the cost of stability. This eect is particularly salient when the surplus
is submodular. Specifically, with complete information, 94% of our supermodular markets cul-
minate in ecient, positively assortative outcomes and 78% of market results are stable. When
preferences are submodular, only 73% of our markets yield ecient, negatively assortative out-
comes and a mere 14% of ultimate outcomes are stable.
When information is incomplete, the theoretical literature oers little guidance as to the dy-
namics and outcomes one might expect; see our review of the literature. In particular, there is
little work inspecting the information revealed through the operations of a market that starts
1
While markets’ termination depends on all market participants ceasing activity, any particular pair can stop search-
ing for alternatives sooner by maintaining their pairing till the market ends.
2
Oers still entail the specification of a transfer. Absent information on match surpluses, certain oers can lead
to negative payos. We allow participants to cancel such oers ex-post. We do not see participants “gaming” the
experiments through this option.
3
Utilitarian ecient matchings maximize the sum of match surpluses. Stability with transfers corresponds to a
matching and a profile of transfers such that no pair of agents can find a transfer that, if implemented, would make
their match desirable relative to what they already receive. It is well known that stable matchings are utilitarian
ecient (e.g. Roth and Sotomayor, 1990).
3
with incomplete information. In simple incomplete-information markets such as ours, where par-
ticipants enter with considerable information and every accepted or rejected oer yields more
information, interactions could plausibly lead to complete information. Therefore, throughout
much of our analysis, we use complete-information stability as a benchmark, returning to this
issue in Section 5.1.
In our data, incomplete information and submodularity constitute substantial obstacles to
both eciency and stability. Indeed, with incomplete information, in markets with a supermod-
ular surplus structure, 84% of outcomes are ecient, while 54% are stable. With submodular
surpluses, 39% of outcomes are ecient, and a mere 3% are stable. In other words, the combina-
tion of incomplete information with submodularity nearly eliminates the likelihood of achieving
stable outcomes. This observation opens the door for richer theories of matching with incom-
plete information: ones that allow for some market learning, but still yield outcomes that are not
complete-information stable.
The analysis of oer dynamics provides a lens into how market outcomes are generated. When
information is complete, markets governed by supermodular surpluses “match from the top,”
in the sense that high-type agents (who generate the greatest surplus) match first, followed by
medium-type agents, and finally low-type agents.
4
In contrast, the sequenceing of matches is
more haphazard in submodular markets. Many more oers are made throughout those market
operations. Early matches that “stick” are often between high-type agents, and generate a barrier
to achieving market-wide eciency. Medium-type agents follow suit, while low-type agents tend
to match late, regardless of their partner’s type.
When information is incomplete, regardless of the underlying surplus structure, initial matches
are often transient and broken later in the market’s operations as participants learn. This leads to
far more market activity. Matches between incongruent types, low and high, occur earlier. Inter-
estingly, the enhanced market activity we observe implies that, by the end of our markets’ oper-
ations, most participants learn with whom they can generate which surplus, consistent with our
focus on complete-information stability. However, even matches formed later in our incomplete-
information markets do not echo the patterns seen in their complete-information counterparts.
Why do outcomes not mimic those in our complete-information markets? We show that our data
4
This sequence resembles the Marshallian path studied by Plott, Roy, and Tong (2013).
4
are consistent with simple satisficing heuristics of participants. Based on their type, participants
aim at a certain payo and actively search for partners only below their satisficing threshold. This
observation echoes evidence documented in individual decision-making; see Caplin, Dean, and
Martin (2011). In our setting, satisficing emerges through dynamic market interactions.
A large literature, scientific and popular, suggests the importance of bargaining strategies
in determining outcomes—for reviews, see Bertrand (2011) and Shell (2006). One may wonder
whether our participants’ individual tendencies help explain their obtained payos. We indeed
see large variation in individuals’ bargaining styles, in terms of oer volume, number of matches
created throughout a market, how demanding oers are, and the timing of interactions. Nonethe-
less, none of these has any substantial explanatory power for outcomes. Ultimately, market fea-
tures and ones position in the market—namely, the type—appear to explain the lions share of the
payos participants receive. This result may be comforting to some: while individual characteris-
tics and access to opportunities for self-improvement may greatly aect ones consequences, they
do so only insofar as they alter one’s position, or “quality,” in the market. Once in the market,
outcomes appear resilient to individual variations that go beyond participants’ contributions to
the surpluses they can generate.
Implications. Taken together, our results carry several important implications for market de-
sign. First, when transfers are available, stability through decentralized interaction is not guaran-
teed and depends crucially on the underlying preferences in the market. In particular, centralized
clearinghouses may be especially beneficial when preferences are submodular. Second, incom-
plete information presents a substantial hurdle for achieving stability. Interventions directed at
alleviating information frictions may therefore prove useful. Such interventions could entail al-
lowing for more communication between participants, introducing public releases of information
about market attributes, etc. Alternatively, centralization of the matching process may be par-
ticularly important when participants are not perfectly informed. The existing literature rarely
considers clearinghouses with imperfectly-informed participants, and the consideration of those
may be necessary. Last, educating participants to achieve their maximal potential “quality” as
they enter a matching market may be of far greater importance than educating participants on
how to negotiate their interactions once in the market.
5
1.2 Related Literature
A large theoretical literature considers matching markets with complete information, with or
without transfers; see Roth and Sotomayor (1990). Incomplete information poses many challenges
to the analysis of matching markets. Even the basic stability notion is dicult to translate when
agents are not fully informed of everyones preferences. Pairs that would block a matching with
complete information—pairs of agents that prefer one another over their allocated match—may
not form if agents cannot discern who would prefer a match with them. Furthermore, any at-
tempt to form a blocking pair allows other participants to partially infer the preferences of agents
involved, possibly others’ when those are correlated.
Starting from Liu, Mailath, Postlewaite, and Samuelson (2014), several recent papers suggest
stability notions for incomplete information markets, mostly restricting attention to incomplete
information only on one market side. Bikhchandani (2017) considers matching markets without
transfers. Liu et al. (2014), and relatedly Alston (2020) and Liu (2022), consider matching with
transfers as we do. At the heart of the stability notions in these papers is the requirement that any
agents “deviation from a matching, with its attendant transfers, ultimately leaves her (weakly)
worse o. The stability notions in these papers are defined with respect to a given matching and
a fixed specification of the uncertainty agents have about others’ types. They do not consider the
possibility that the match formation process may reveal information, rendering the specification
of uncertainty endogenous and possibly leading to eectively complete information.
Stability notions are interesting due to the presumption that, in frictionless decentralized mar-
kets, agents would ultimately converge to a stable outcome. Nonetheless, only a few papers explic-
itly model the decentralized process that generates such stable outcomes. Roth and Vate (1990)
oer non-strategic dynamics that yield stable outcomes, whereby at each stage, a random block-
ing pair is implemented. Complete information is implicitly assumed, as all blocking pairs are
considered at every step. Ferdowsian, Niederle, and Yariv (2022) consider a decentralized mar-
ket game in which firms and workers interact in a dynamic fashion. They illustrate the hurdles
incomplete information or time frictions generate in establishing stability as a property of equi-
librium outcomes. Chen and Hu (2020) focus on incomplete-information settings and construct
an adaptive learning process leading to stable outcomes as they define them.
Hakimov and Kübler (2021) present a general overview of the experimental matching liter-
6
ature. Several papers in that literature share features with our design.
5
Concurrent work by
He, Wu, and Zhang (2022) considers decentralized matching with complete information, allow-
ing for transfers between participants. He et al. (2022)’s design resembles that of our complete-
information treatment, although their experimental markets have a pre-specified time of opera-
tion.
6
In line with our results, they observe far more stable outcomes in assortative than in anti-
assortative markets. In contrast with our results, they observe a substantial fraction of unmatched
individuals, potentially due to the limited-market horizon. Outside the matching context, Agra-
nov and Elliott (2021) identify the important impacts of transfers on bargaining outcomes.
Nalbantian and Schotter (1995) report on experiments emulating the market for professional
baseball players in the free-agent years. They analyze several allocation procedures with trans-
fers, including a decentralized procedure in which agents are informed of their own bargaining
outcomes, but not of others’. Pais, Pintér, and Veszteg (2020) study decentralized markets with
multiple stable matchings. There are no transfers and markets operate over a fixed duration. In
some treatments, participants are privately informed of their preferences. Incomplete informa-
tion in their setting does not aect the stability or the eciency of the final outcome. However,
similar to what we observe, it boosts market activity. Niederle and Roth (2009) study unrav-
eling by considering an incomplete-information setting in which one side of the market makes
proposals to the other side over three experimental periods and information is exogenously and
incrementally released. They illustrate the impact of proposal structure on matching outcomes
and eciency. Incomplete information has also been considered in centralized markets, mostly
focusing on school-choice mechanisms and, therefore, absent transfers. See, for example, Chen
and Sönmez (2006), Pais and Pintér (2008), and work that followed.
7
2 Experimental Protocol
In our experiments, participants engage in a sequence of decentralized markets varying in two
dimensions: the surplus structure, which is either supermodular or submodular, and the infor-
mation available. In some matching markets, participants are fully informed of everyones pref-
5
There are also several papers studying decentralized matching with complete information and no transfers, see
Echenique and Yariv (2013) and references therein.
6
In their design, participants whose match is broken in the last 15 seconds can make oers within 15 seconds.
7
There is also recent empirical work that highlights the consequences of incomplete information in school choice,
see Kapor, Neilson, and Zimmerman (2020).
7
Table 1: Match Surpluses (Ecient Allocation in Bold)
Kiwi Mango Plum
Blue 8 16 24
Crimson 16 32 48
White 24 48 72
(a) Supermodular
Kiwi Mango Plum
Blue 8 32 56
Crimson 32 48 64
White 56 64 72
(b) Submodular
erences, in others they receive only partial information. We describe each of these dimensions in
turn. Sample experimental instructions are presented in Online Appendix C.
Our two-sided one-to-one matching markets are comprised of six participants, three on each
side. Each participant has a role: a color or a food. These roles capture the market sides and can
be metaphors for firms and workers in labor markets, men and women in the marriage market,
etc. There are three payo-relevant types for each role. Specifically, the three color types are Blue,
Crimson, and White. The three food types are Kiwi, Mango, and Plum. A matching specifies
which colors and foods are unmatched, as well as a mapping between the remaining colors and
foods that is one-to-one: if a color type, say Blue, is assigned to a food type, say Kiwi, then the
reverse holds as well: Kiwi is assigned to Blue.
8
Table 1 depicts the match surpluses governing preferences in our markets. Panel (a) corre-
sponds to our supermodular surpluses, while panel (b) captures our submodular surpluses. In
each, the entry corresponding to each color and food pair is the match surplus generated by that
pair. Unmatched agents receive a payo of 0.
We consider two information structures. In our complete-information treatments, partici-
pants are fully informed of surpluses generated by all pairs in the market. In particular, they
can readily rank their potential partners in terms of the surpluses they would jointly generate. In
our incomplete-information treatments, participants know their own type: at the markets outset,
they are informed of the three possible surpluses they can generate with the three potential part-
ners on the other side of the market. However, they do not know which partner generates which
surplus, nor which of the remaining two types have been assigned to which other agent on their
side of the market. Formally, we permute the type labels in markets and inform participants only
of their own type. The structure of payos is transparent, as well as the randomization procedure.
The general structure of each session is as follows. The governing match surpluses, either su-
8
In our experimental results, the incidence of unmatched participants is only 0.5% across all sessions.
8
permodular or submodular, as well as the information structure, are fixed throughout the session.
Participants engage in one practice round, followed by 10 real rounds, each corresponding to a
new market (of the same sort in terms of both preferences and information), with a freshly drawn
random set of participants within the session. Participants maintain their role, a color or a food,
throughout the session. However, in each round, they are randomly assigned one of the three
types corresponding to their role.
In our complete-information treatments, each participant observes the full surplus matrix
throughout every round.
9
In our incomplete-information treatments, each participant only ob-
serves her own possible match surpluses at the start of each round.
10
As we soon explain, inter-
actions in the market can reveal some information on who generates which surplus.
We now describe the rules of the matching protocol. In each round, participants start o un-
matched. Each participant is free to make at most one match proposal to any individual of the
opposite role at any given time. In the complete-information treatments, a match proposal speci-
fies how the match surplus will be split among the two individuals—i.e., the proposer’s payo and
the responder’s payo, summing up to the match surplus. In the incomplete-information treat-
ments, a match proposal only specifies the responder’s payo, with the attendant proposer payo
revealed if the responder accepts. Thus, the proposer bears the payo risk under incomplete infor-
mation. This design choice was made to echo many applications in which the proposing side has
limited information on the returns to her proposal. For instance, firms oering employment often
cannot assess workers’ abilities. Nonetheless, we limited the scope of risk by allowing proposers
to immediately retract an oer if it turned out to generate a strict loss. For example, suppose Blue
and Kiwi generate a match surplus of 8. If Blue oers Kiwi a payo of 16, and Kiwi accepts, then
Blue earns a payo of -8. Since Blue earns a negative payo, we would allow her to unilaterally
cancel the match.
11
This design choice was made both for practical reasons, in order to limit the
liability participants face, and also to mimic applications in which catastrophic relationships can
be severed promptly. For instance, a worker who does not have their presumed credentials can be
9
To prevent participants from reacting to cosmetic features of the surplus matrix, we shued the rows and columns
of the surplus matrix between rounds. In particular, specific colors and foods correspond to dierent match-surplus
profiles in each round. As a result, the ecient matchings do not always coincide with the diagonal (in the positively
assortative case) or anti-diagonal (in the negatively assortative case) of the surplus matrix.
10
For example, Blue in panel (a) of Table 1 would know that her possible match surpluses are 8, 16, and 24. However,
she would not know which surplus corresponds to which match.
11
In our data, 88% of negative oers were canceled by the proposers immediately. Other cases were associated with
immediate new oers by the proposers. Either way, we never see negative payos for any participant at any round.
9
fired quickly by the firm that hired them in many labor-market settings. Whenever an oer that
gives a positive payo for both parties is accepted, the match can be dissolved only upon one of
its participants making or receiving an alternative oer that is accepted.
A match generating a loss certainly conveys some information to the proposer. In general,
whenever a match proposal is made and accepted, both the proposer and the responder observe
their realized payos. Other participants observe the formation of the match and the responder’s
payo. This is the main channel through which learning occurs under incomplete information.
In terms of market activity, participants are free to accept or reject match proposals they re-
ceive from other individuals. Any match proposal that is not accepted or rejected within 10 sec-
onds automatically disappears and is eectively interpreted as a rejection. An acceptance forms a
match. Participants who are currently matched can still make and receive new match proposals,
with their current match persisting until such a new match proposal is accepted, at which point
(only) the current match is dissolved. A round ends after 30 seconds of inactivity. In incomplete-
information treatments, in order to allow participants to avoid excessive waiting, we introduced a
“move on to next round” button. Whenever at least 5 participants pressed the button, the market
for that group and round terminated.
12
A participant’s payo in their current match at the end
of a round is their final payo for that round. If a participant is unmatched at the end of a round,
their final payo is 0 for that round.
At the end of each session, participants also complete two risk-elicitation tasks and two al-
truism tasks. We use a version of the Gneezy and Potters (1997) investment task to measure
risk preferences and a dictator game to measure altruism.
13
All payos in the experiment are
expressed in tokens. For the main part of the experiment, 10 tokens correspond to $1. For the
elicitation tasks, one token corresponds to $0.01. Participants’ total earnings in the experiment
include a $10 show-up payment, the sum of their final payos across the 10 rounds, and their
payos from the auxiliary elicitation tasks.
12
We were particularly concerned about the sensitivity of our incomplete-information treatments to specific indi-
viduals prolonging rounds after long waits. Whenever 5 of the 6 group members are ready to halt market activity,
we suspected the choice of the sixth individual to delay the end time would not aect outcomes. As will be seen, our
incomplete-information treatments indeed took much longer in terms of both time and market activity.
13
Specifically, in each of the two risk-elicitation tasks, participants were provided with 200 tokens that they had to
allocate between a safe project, returning token for token, and a risky project. In the first task, each token invested in
the risky project returned 2.5 tokens with 50% probability, and 0 otherwise. In the second task, each token invested
returned 3 tokens with 40% probability, and 0 otherwise. Altruism was elicited using two dictator-game elicitations,
one with an endowment of 100 tokens and another with an endowment of 200 tokens.
10
The experimental sessions were run at the Experimental and Behavioral Economics Laboratory
(EBEL) at UC Santa Barbara between July 2018 and October 2018. Each treatment, characterized
by a combination of underlying preferences and information structure, was run in 4 sessions, each
consisting of 12 participants. This generated 16 sessions overall and a total of 192 participants.
Each session lasted approximately 90 minutes, and paid an average of $24.75, in addition to a $10
show-up fee. The experiment was programmed and conducted with the oTree software (Chen,
Schonger, and Wickens, 2016).
3 Theoretical Preliminaries
In both our supermodular and submoduar markets, types can be ordered. In Table 1, White
generates higher surplus than Crimson, who generates higher surplus than Blue, for any food.
Similarly, Plum generates higher surplus than Mango, who generates a higher surplus than Kiwi,
for any color. Since labels of dierent types are shued across rounds, and the two sides of
our markets are fully symmetric, we refer to the types generating the highest surplus as high
types, those generating the intermediate surplus as medium types, and those generating the lowest
surplus as low types.
Formally, let C be the set of colors and F the set of foods, with generic elements f and c.
Let π : C × F R identify the surplus associated with each pair of agents. A matching (with no
unmatched agents) is a bijection m : C F C F, where m(C) F, m(F) C, satisfying the
restriction that if m(c) = f , then m(f ) = c for all c C and f F. An outcome is a matching m and
a pair of transfer schemes τ
C
: C R and τ
F
: F R.
Under complete information, an outcome (m,τ
C
,τ
F
) is stable if it satisfies
τ
C
(c), τ
F
(f ) 0 (c, f ) C × F
τ
C
(c) + τ
F
(m(c)) = π(c,m(c)) c C
τ
C
(c) + τ
F
(f ) π(c, f ) (c,f ) C × F.
The first condition is an individual rationality requirement guaranteeing that no agent prefers to
be unmatched. The second condition is a feasibility condition guaranteeing that transfers in a
matched pair do not exceed the generated surplus. The third condition is a no-blocking condition
11
that guarantees there is no pair of agents who can increase their transfers by matching with one
another and appropriately dividing the attendant surplus. We say that a matching m is stable if it
is consistent with some stable outcome.
While all our treatments allow participants to make transfers to one another, it is useful to
first contemplate a no-transfer benchmark, in which surpluses are divided at some fixed ratios
between the two sides of the market.
14
In this case, there is a unique stable matching in both the
supermodular and submodular markets: the positive assortative matching (PAM) that matches
individuals of the same type. In the markets depicted in Table 1, the unique stable matching
would match the highest types, White and Plum, then the medium types, Crimson and Mango,
and finally the low types, Blue and Kiwi.
When transfers are available, stable outcomes induce matchings that maximize the sum of
surpluses: the utilitarian ecient matchings, hereafter referred to as simply ecient. For the
two markets we consider, there may be many transfer profiles that sustain stable outcomes, see
Appendix B for a formal characterization, but the matching itself is unique. In our supermod-
ular markets, the matching maximizing utilitarian eciency is the positive assortative matching
(PAM). Furthermore, PAM together with transfers that split each surplus equally constitute a sta-
ble outcome. In our submodular markets, the matching maximizing utilitarian eciency is the
negative assortative matching (NAM). Importantly, there is no stable outcome in which each sur-
plus is split equally. Instead, in the matches between low and high agents (Blue with Plum and
White with Kiwi), the high agents (White and Plum) must receive more than half the surplus.
The existing theoretical literature oers less definitive guidance as to the behavior and out-
comes one might expect under incomplete information. We adopt a permissive analog of complete-
information stability, deeming an outcome as unstable if there is a pair of agents with the property
that (i) one of the agents can propose matching under terms that will make both agents better o,
and (ii) the proposing agent knows there is no chance the proposal could make her worse o.
To make this precise, for each color c, let the set E
c
R
3
, with generic element (π(c,·)), con-
tain vectors specifying the surpluses that c can generate with each food f . Let E
f
be similarly
defined for each food f . We say that the set E
c
(or E
f
) is consistent with color cs (or food f s)
experience if it excludes those values that the experience has revealed to be impossible. Then
14
That is, we can restrict τ(c) = απ(c,m(c)) and τ(f ) = (1 α)π(m(f ),f ) for all c and f , where α (0,1).
12
(m,τ
C
,τ
F
,(E
c
)
cC
,(E
f
)
f F
) is incomplete-information stable if the sets (E
c
)
cC
,(E
f
)
f F
are consis-
tent and
τ
C
(c), τ
F
(f ) 0 (c, f ) C × F
τ
C
(c) + τ
F
(m(c)) = π(c,m(c)) c C
τ
C
(c) + τ
F
(f ) min
(
˜
π(c,·))E
c
˜
π(c,f ) c C
τ
C
(c) + τ
F
(f ) min
(
˜
π(·,f ))E
f
˜
π(c,f ) f F.
The first two conditions are the individual rationality and feasibility conditions. The latter two
conditions are the no-blocking conditions, stated separately for colors and foods. For example, the
colors’ no-blocking condition asks each color c to identify the minimum surplus generated with
each food f , given what c has learned. The condition guarantees that no split of that (pessimistic)
surplus can leave both c and f better o. The last condition is the analog for foods.
If at least one of the participants in each possible match knows the surplus that would be gen-
erated by the match, then this notion of incomplete-information stability reduces to complete-
information stability. This sucient condition will be met in our case if at least 5 market par-
ticipants know the surplus they can generate with each opponent. Our results (Table 5 below)
show that the average number of participants who learn from their direct experience—i.e., from
matches in which they have at least temporarily participated—the surpluses they can generate
with each opponent exceeds 5. The matching process provides yet more information. We accord-
ingly take complete-information stability as our benchmark throughout.
Despite the abundance of information participants accumulate through market interactions,
we show that our incomplete-information markets do not routinely produce stable outcomes. In
latter parts of the paper, we consider two explanations. First, market participants may make
use of even less information than that which they have gained through their direct experience.
Second, incomplete information may introduce glitches into the matching process beyond the lack
of information—some oers a potential proposer knows impose no risk of a reduced payo and
benefit both parties involved, may not be made. In particular, participants may pursue decision
criteria dierent from payo maximization. Our analysis indicates the room for a richer theory of
matching with incomplete information.
13
4 Aggregate Outcomes
We start by describing the aggregate outcomes in our experimental markets. We use all 10 rounds
played in each session and omit the practice round.
4.1 Eciency and Stability
Table 2 depicts the fraction of ecient outcomes, those corresponding to a matching that maxi-
mizes the sum of match surpluses, i.e. the fraction of PAM for supermodular markets and NAM
for submodular markets. The table also depicts the fraction of stable outcomes, consisting of both
an ecient matching and a stable transfer profile. For the latter, we also display the fraction of
outcomes that are “almost stable” in that the matching is ecient, and no pair can generate more
than a small additional amount, 2 or 5 tokens, by blocking the observed outcome.
Table 2: Final Outcomes (allocations)
Complete Information Incomplete Information
Supermodular Submodular Supermodular Submodular
mean (se) mean (se) mean (se) mean (se)
Eciency 0.94 (0.04) 0.73 (0.07) 0.84 (0.04) 0.39 (0.10)
Matching
PAM 0.94 (0.04) 0.01 (0.01) 0.84 (0.04) 0.08 (0.06)
NAM 0.00 (0.00) 0.73 (0.07) 0.00 (0.00) 0.39 (0.10)
Stability
exact 0.78 (0.10) 0.14 (0.09) 0.54 (0.07) 0.03 (0.03)
- 2 tokens 0.89 (0.06) 0.33 (0.11) 0.68 (0.06) 0.06 (0.05)
- 5 tokens 0.93 (0.05) 0.58 (0.12) 0.78 (0.06) 0.19 (0.11)
Notes: Robust standard errors (reported in parentheses) are obtained by clustering at the session level to account for
interdependencies of observations that come from the same session. An ecient outcome is one that maximizes the sum
of match surpluses. PAM indicates positive-assortative matching, while NAM indicates negative-assortative matching.
An allocation is stable (or stable x tokens) if the matching is utilitarian ecient and no pair can generate any gain (of
more than x tokens) by blocking the observed outcome.
Table 2 suggests several insights. First, a substantial fraction of all of our markets culminates
in ecient matchings. For the most part, matchings are positively assortative when PAM is e-
cient and negatively assortative when NAM is ecient.
Second, incomplete information poses an important obstacle for eciency, particularly for
submodular markets. For supermodular markets, moving from complete to incomplete infor-
14
mation generates a reduction of 10 percentage points in the fraction of ecient matchings. In
contrast, for our submodular markets, the fraction of ecient matchings almost halves, dropping
by 34 percentage points.
Third, there are fewer stable than ecient outcomes. Much of the instability we observe is due
to unstable transfer profiles, as captured by the dierence between the fraction of outcomes that
entail an ecient matching and those that are stable. For example, with complete information, 6%
of supermodular markets do not culminate in an ecient matching, while 16% of supermodular
markets yield an ecient matching but with unstable transfers. This wedge is even more pro-
nounced for submodular markets. With complete information, 27% of markets do not culminate
in ecient matchings, while 59% produce an ecient matching with unstable transfers.
Fourth, the surplus structure has important impacts on whether emergent outcomes are sta-
ble. Submodular markets generate significantly and substantially fewer stable outcomes than do
supermodular markets, especially under incomplete information, with dierences that are more
pronounced than the comparisons of ecient outcomes. With complete information, 78% of su-
permodular markets culminate in a stable outcome, while for submodular markets, the corre-
sponding figure is 14%. This is the case even when allowing for minimal “mistakes” in terms of
the transfer profile. With incomplete information, the fraction of stable outcomes in supermod-
ular markets falls to 54%, while the fraction of stable outcomes in submodular markets nearly
vanishes, standing at 3%.
These comparisons are mirrored by the pattern of blocking pairs. For supermodular markets,
unstable outcomes are associated with an average of 1.56 blocking pairs with complete informa-
tion and an average of 1.65 blocking pairs with incomplete information. The corresponding fig-
ures for our submodular markets are 1.67 and 2.86. In particular, with incomplete information,
submodular preferences yield significantly more blocking pairs than supermodular preferences
(at the 1% significance level). The patterns are more pronounced when considering ecient, but
unstable, outcomes. In those, we see an average of one blocking pair with complete information
and an average of 1.25 blocking pairs with incomplete information when surpluses are super-
modular. The figures for our submodular markets are 1.32 and 1.93, both significantly higher (at
the 1% significance levels). A similar pattern emerges when considering the average surplus gen-
erated by blocking pairs of unstable outcomes, with incomplete information and submodularity
15
leading to greater average surplus available across blocking pairs.
15
These results suggest that,
even with fairly unrestricted and decentralized interactions, market participants facing incom-
plete information are not gleaning enough information to attain complete-information stability.
4.2 Payos
Table 3 provides aggregate statistics of participants’ payos and transfers. The top panel of the
table depicts the average payos by type. Theoretically, all stable outcomes of our supermodular
markets entail higher types gaining greater payos. In our submodular markets, however, a uni-
form distribution over stable outcomes would yield only 50% of stable transfer profiles exhibiting
this monotonic pattern (see our Appendix B for details on the constraints stability with transfers
imposes). Interestingly, when considering average payments, in all of our treatments we see high
types garnering significantly greater payos than medium types, who end up with significantly
greater payos than low types. Nonetheless, when we consider these comparisons market by mar-
ket, we see some dierences, echoing our theoretical predictions. When information is complete,
all of our supermodular markets, but only 83% of our submodular markets, end up with higher
types gaining greater payos. When information is incomplete, 93% of our supermodular markets
and 61% of our submodular markets generate greater payos for higher types.
Equal splits are common in experimental work (e.g. Andreoni and Bernheim, 2009). While
equal splits are consistent with stability for supermodular markets, that is not the case for sub-
modular markets. In fact, were participants simply following an egalitarian norm and always
proposing an equal split of match surpluses, we would expect to observe PAM outcomes in all
our markets, as described in Section 3. Table 2 suggests that egalitarian norms cannot be medi-
ating all of our results. Indeed, in our submodular markets, we see PAM outcomes quite rarely.
In fact, while the transfers required for stable outcomes seem elusive, particularly in submodular
markets, the overall eciency in those markets is far greater than under PAM. While PAM would
generate a total surplus of 128 tokens, the top panel of Table 3 indicates an average total surplus
of 157.5 tokens under complete information and an average total surplus of 150.5 tokens under
incomplete information. In other words, transfers do allow for greater eciency, even in cases in
15
In supermodular markets that culminated in an unstable outcome, the average surplus available to blocking pairs
was 7.06 tokens with complete information and 7.19 tokens with incomplete information. For submodular markets,
the corresponding figures were 5.33 and 7.90 tokens. In particular, the greatest number of blocking pairs and available
surplus per blocking pair were observed for submodular markets with incomplete information.
16
Table 3: Players’ Final Payos
Complete Information Incomplete Information
Supermodular Submodular Supermodular Submodular
mean (se) mean (se) mean (se) mean (se)
Payos by Type
Low Type 4.11 (0.06) 16.07 (0.37) 4.41 (0.15) 14.72 (0.60)
Medium Type 15.83 (0.12) 23.81 (0.25) 15.60 (0.51) 24.19 (0.14)
High Type 35.86 (0.10) 38.87 (0.45) 35.29 (0.27) 36.33 (0.54)
Equal Splits
All allocations 0.79 (0.04) 0.32 (0.01) 0.67 (0.06) 0.39 (0.06)
First two deals 0.64 (0.03) 0.60 (0.03) 0.15 (0.01) 0.23 (0.02)
Ecient allocations 0.81 (0.03) 0.31 (0.01) 0.69 (0.05) 0.29 (0.02)
Stable allocations 0.87 (0.02) 0.30 (0.01) 0.80 (0.06) 0.33 (0.21)
Notes: Average payos by players’ types are reported in the first three rows. Robust standard errors are clustered at
the session level and reported in the parentheses. Equal splits correspond to ratios of payos between two matched
players falling between 45% and 55%. For the first two deals in the incomplete-information markets, we focus on deals
in which the proposer receives non-negative payos.
which stability appears the most challenging to achieve.
The bottom panel of Table 3 displays explicitly the frequency of (roughly) 50 50 splits of
the match surplus in the final outcomes observed across markets. In order to allow for some
margin of error, we consider oers that range from 45% to 55% of the surplus. Since there are
many opportunities for participants to learn their match surpluses with others through markets’
operations—see Section 5.2 below—we consider the possibility of equal splits for incomplete-
information markets as well. Such roughly equal splits are prevalent, albeit not universal, in our
supermodular markets: hovering around 80% with complete information and around 70% with
incomplete information. They are far less common in our submodular markets, comprising fewer
than 40% of the outcomes regardless of the information available.
16
Figure 1 describes the cumulative distribution functions corresponding to payos across our
treatments. While complete-information treatments generally yield more pronounced “jumps”
the underlying preferences have a clear impact. With supermodular preferences, many of the
payos take one of three values. Indeed, when superimposing the distribution of payos that
would be generated by equally splitting the surplus between agents in the ecient matching (the
16
Interestingly, when looking at initial accepted oers in our markets, we see far more equal shares of match sur-
pluses for matches between congruent types in our submodular markets. In the first two accepted oers, equal sharing
occurs in over 89% of deals between participants of the same type. Nonetheless, even in these additional deals, partic-
ipants of dierent types do not split the surpluses equally. In particular, low types matching with high types get only
20% of the surplus. We provide more details on behavior at the start of our markets’ operations in Appendix A.
17
Figure 1: Cumulative Distributions of Players’ Payos
0
.2
.4
.6
.8
1
Cumulative Probability
0 10 20 30 40 50
Players' Payoffs
Complete Supermodular Complete Submodular
Incomplete Supermodular Incomplete Submodular
orange solid line, corresponding to equal masses receiving payos of 4, 16, and 36), we see sub-
stantial overlap. Submodular preferences, however, yield a nearly uniform distribution of payos,
particularly when information is incomplete. With complete information, we do see a large frac-
tion of individuals receiving a payo of 24, an observation we soon elaborate on. Furthermore, the
payo distributions corresponding to submodular preferences first order stochastically dominate
those corresponding to supermodular preferences. This, again, suggests that participants are not
simply implementing the ecient matching and splitting the surplus in those markets. Indeed,
the resulting distribution (depicted in the blue solid line, corresponding to one third of the popu-
lation receiving a payo of 24 and two thirds receiving a payo of 28) would second order, but not
first order, stochastically dominate the corresponding distribution for our supermodular markets.
Figure 1 presents payo distributions aggregated across all market participants. At first blush,
it indicates similarity in overall payo distributions between complete- and incomplete-information
markets of the same surplus variety. Figure 2 presents the distribution of payos by types of
agents in markets that culminated in “nearly stable” outcomes, ones in which the matching is e-
cient and there is a stable allocation of the surpluses such that each participant’s payo is at most
2 tokens away from what they would receive in that allocation.
17
The figure depicts how observed
17
Allowing for a small margin of error ensures that the samples we discuss are of sucient size.
18
Figure 2: Distribution of Payos by Types in Stable (-$2) Allocations
0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Fraction
0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32
Submodular: Low Types
0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Fraction
0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32
Supermodular: Low Types
0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Fraction
0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40
Supermodular: Medium Types
0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Fraction
0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40
Submodular: Medium Types
0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Fraction
20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 52 56
Supermodular: High Types
0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Fraction
20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 52 56
Submodular: High Types
PayoffsHighStableT2Sub 5/31/20, 11:38 AM
0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Fraction
20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 52 56
Complete Incomplete
Submodular: High Types
Notes: The red line on the horizontal axis of each graph depicts the range of payos corresponding to stable outcomes
predicted by theory.
payos relate to the range of payos corresponding to stable outcomes, captured by the red solid
line in each panel (see Appendix B for computational details). In line with our discussion above,
the distribution of payos for all agents and across our markets exhibits a spike at the midpoint
of stable allocations. However, the figure conveys several additional messages. Considering our
complete-information treatments, payos corresponding to the midpoint of the interval of stable
transfers are far more prevalent in our supermodular markets. In fact, in our submodular mar-
kets, while over 70% of the medium-type agents receive the mid-point of their stable payos, low-
and high-type agents have far more disperse payo distributions. With incomplete information,
payos are noticeably more diuse, particularly when preferences are submodular. In fact, for
submodular preferences, for all types, no allocation carries more than 30% of our data.
4.3 Market Activity
Table 4 summarizes the aggregate features of activity in our markets. As can be seen, market
activity took, on average, between 3 and 5 minutes. Our incomplete-information markets corre-
19
Table 4: Market Characteristics
Complete Information Incomplete Information
Supermodular Submodular Supermodular Submodular
mean (se) mean (se) mean (se) mean (se)
Market duration (in sec) 158.6 (14.0) 171.5 (16.1) 191.6 (16.5) 292.9 (10.6)
Nb of oers extended
overall per market 24.8 (1.5) 24.1 (3.0) 42.4 (4.3) 45.9 (5.3)
by Low type 9.6 (1.4) 10.7 (2.0) 19.9 (1.5) 21.0 (2.7)
by Medium type 8.0 (0.8) 8.4 (0.7) 14.2 (2.0) 15.8 (2.2)
by High type 7.2 (0.8) 5.2 (0.3) 8.3 (0.9) 9.1 (1.4)
Nb of oers accepted
overall per market 5.6 (0.3) 8.8 (1.3) 15.9 (1.0) 17.3 (1.1)
by Low type 1.7 (0.04) 2.1 (0.26) 5.9 (0.36) 5.7 (0.38)
by Medium type 2.1 (0.16) 3.1 (0.48) 5.9 (0.48) 5.7 (0.35)
by High type 1.8 (0.12) 3.5 (0.55) 4.2 (0.43) 6.0 (0.37)
Notes: Robust standard errors are clustered at the session level and reported in parentheses.
spond to significantly longer durations and a greater volume of oers made and accepted. Our
submodular markets correspond to somewhat longer times to reach an outcome. However, the
volume of oers made or accepted does not seem to hinge on the underlying preference structure.
At the aggregate level, there are no great dierences across agent types in terms of overall oers
made or accepted. One exception corresponds to the low-type agents, who make significantly
more oers than the high-type agents, particularly when information is incomplete.
4.4 Summary of Aggregate Outcomes
Overall, participants often establish ecient matchings. Stability is more elusive, indicating that
it is easier to settle on an ecient matching than to arrange the attendant transfers. Incomplete
information and submodular surplus structures present hurdles to eciency and especially sta-
bility, with the combination of incomplete information and submodularity reducing stability to a
tiny percentage of outcomes. Incomplete information appears to introduce “complexity” in that
markets with incomplete information take longer to converge and involve substantially more par-
ticipant interactions to reach an outcome.
20
5 Market Dynamics
5.1 Match Evolution
Figure 3: Transient and Permanent Matches, by Quintiles
Complete
Supermodular
Quintile 1 Quintile 2
Quintile 3 Quintile 4 Quintile 5
PayoffsHighStableT2Sub 5/31/20, 11:38 AM
0 .2 .4 .6 .8
Fraction
20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 52 56
Complete Incomplete
Submodular: High Types
TransientPermanent
Complete
Submodular
Incomplete
Supermodular
Incomplete
Submodular
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
1. 2
1. 4
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
1. 2
1. 4
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
1. 2
1. 4
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
1. 2
1. 4
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
1. 2
1. 4
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
1. 2
1. 4
1. 6
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
1. 2
1. 4
1. 6
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
1. 2
1. 4
1. 6
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
1. 2
1. 4
1. 6
LL MM HH LM LH MH
0
0. 2
0. 4
0. 6
0. 8
1
1. 2
1. 4
1. 6
LL MM HH LM LH MH
Notes: Quintiles are defined relative to the total time the average market takes to reach a final outcome, where average
market duration is calculated as the mean time dierence between the last and first activity in that market. The white
parts of the bars indicate the transient matches, i.e. those that are broken later on. Grey bars depict the final matches
that remain intact until the market’s termination.
We start by considering the progression of matches over the course of a market’s operation. In
order to depict our markets’ evolution, we inspect quintiles of activity in each markets operation.
Namely, for each round in our sessions, we consider the time between the first and last moments
of activity. We split that time span into five quintiles, thereby eectively normalizing the length
of activity in each of our experimental markets.
21
Figure 3 reports the mean number of transient and permanent matches formed at each quin-
tile of market duration across treatments, for each combination of matched types—LL denotes
two low-type agents, LM denotes one low- and one medium-type agent, and so on. Several obser-
vations emerge. First, there are substantial dierences in match dynamics across supermodular
and submodular markets. The complete-information treatments are particularly telling. With
supermodular preferences, both transient and permanent matches are first formed between the
high-type agents. They are followed by medium-type agents, and last by low-type agents. In
contrast, with submodular preferences, extremal types form matches first: we see the most early
transient matches between medium- and high-type agents and the most early permanent matches
between low- and high-type agents. These are followed by matches between congruent medium-
type agents. The early permanent matches between low- and high-type agents occur at substan-
tially lower rates than the corresponding congruent and permanent early matches in our super-
modular markets, particularly when accounting for the fact that each market contains two incon-
gruent low- and high-type pairs. Last, we see a substantial fraction of matches between low- and
medium-type agents at later market phases. These late matches are not part of stable outcomes.
The second observation from Figure 3 is that incomplete-information treatments are associ-
ated with far more oers, in every quintile and particularly early on. Some of these oers act to re-
veal information about the types of agents on the other side of the market—indeed, early-quintile
oers are frequently transient. This presumably explains why some features of the complete-
information markets remain. Specifically, we see more transient and permanent early matches
involving high-type agents. In contrast, the lower-type agents take more time to find partners.
18
5.2 Learning through Market Operations
As incomplete-information markets evolve, participants have opportunities to learn others’ types.
Indeed, whenever an oer is accepted, individuals learn the resulting payos and can thus identify
the type of individual on the other side of the market. Table 5 documents this type of learning
throughout quintiles of our sessions. In both supermodular and submodular markets, by the
18
Repeat oers occur frequently, even in later parts of markets’ operations. Consider the average fraction of repeat
oers in the second half of each round. In complete-information supermodular markets, these range from 0.27 for
low-type agents to 0.34 for medium-type agents to 0.13 for high-type agents. In incomplete-information supermodular
markets, these range from 0.34 for low-type agents to 0.29 for medium-type agents to 0.25 for high-type agents. Our
submodular markets yield nearly identical frequencies of repeat oers.
22
Table 5: Discovering Partners in Incomplete Information Markets
Quintile 1 Quintile 2 Quintile 3 Quintile 4 Quintile 5
Supermodular
all players know partners (frac of markets) 0.14 0.38 0.51 0.56 0.60
av # of players who know their partners 3.38 4.84 5.18 5.29 5.41
Submodular
all players know partners (frac of markets) 0.21 0.41 0.63 0.65 0.80
av # of players who know their partners 3.44 4.75 5.35 5.40 5.66
Notes: For each type of market, supermodular or submodular, we report the fraction of markets in which all players
discover their partners’ surpluses in the corresponding quintile (the first row) and the average number of players (out
of six) who discover their partners’ surpluses in each quintile (the second row).
third quintile, all participants are fully informed about the surpluses they can generate with all
those on the other side of the market in over 50% of markets, with an average of over 5 out of 6
participants being informed. By the termination of each market, these numbers are even higher.
19
The experimental protocol also ensures that whenever a match is formed, everyone learns the
payo of the participant accepting the corresponding oer.
Having 5 out of 6 participants informed is sucient for our stability notion to coincide with
complete-information stability, see Section 3. The dearth of stable outcomes in our incomplete-
information treatments is thus puzzling. The following subsection suggests explanations.
5.3 Patterns of Market Interactions
Matching theory provides limited guidance on the equilibrating dynamics one might expect in
decentralized markets with transfers. We now discuss how certain beliefs might be consistent with
a modified version of stability explaining our markets’ outcomes. We also illustrate behaviors in
our data consistent with participants following a satisficing heuristic, reducing substantially their
eorts once hitting a (type-dependent) payo target.
5.3.1 Stability with Pessimistic Beliefs
Suppose that instead of using all the information participants learn from their market interac-
tions, they assemble only the minimal information consistent with the observed final matching.
19
Learning in submodular markets appears slightly faster than in our supermodular markets. However, this dier-
ence is significant only in the last quintile. Indeed, regression analysis clustering errors at the session level suggests a
corresponding p-value of p = 0.026 when looking at the last quintile, whereas p > 0.10 for earlier quintiles.
23
Suppose, further, that participants form pessimistic expectations (from the point of view of block-
ing), recognizing the possible match surpluses in the market. Namely, when observing a match
in which the receiver realizes a payo of x, they assume the matched partner receives the max-
imal feasible payo of 72 x. Then, in those incomplete-information outcomes that fail to be
complete-information stable, there is an average of only 0.59 blocking pairs in the supermodular
markets and 1.04 blocking pairs in the submodular markets. These numbers are considerably
smaller than those reported above for our complete-information markets (1.56 and 1.67, respec-
tively). This indicates that there are beliefs consistent with the information revealed under which
participants come as close to stable outcomes as they do under complete information. In prac-
tice, we might expect participants to be less pessimistic and to glean yet more information from
the matching process (though perhaps not as much as do the hyper-rational agents in theoret-
ical treatments of incomplete-information stability such as Liu et al., 2014). We conclude that
the matching process in incomplete-information markets does not convey enough information to
bring the agents to complete-information stability. We leave as an important topic for future work
the more refined investigation of whether the resulting behavior reflects stability on the part of
timid, under-inferring agents, or failures of less timid and more clever agents to achieve stability.
While pessimistic beliefs provide an eective way to organize the market outcomes we observe,
they do not, on their own, explain the dynamics markets follow.
20
In what follows, we illustrate a
simple heuristic consistent with the market activity we observe.
5.3.2 Satisficing Patterns
We now consider a satisficing heuristic, whereby participants target a particular payo, possibly
dependent on their market type. Caplin et al. (2011) document the use and prevalence of sat-
isficing heuristics in individual choices. Our design allows for satisficing behavior to emerge in
a market setting, where the satisficing threshold depends on global market features. Satisficing
would suggest that participants make oers before hitting their target payo, and cease making
oers once that target is achieved.
For each market, we compute the number of oers made by players of each type—low, medium,
20
For instance, pessimistic beliefs at the start of each market’s activity could correspond to each participant sus-
pecting the minimal match surplus available to them. However, initial oers in our incomplete-information markets
significantly exceed half that surplus for each of the three types. Furthermore, initial oers do not reflect a persistent
fraction other than 50% of that “pessimistic” surplus.
24
or high—conditional on their current payo, excluding unmatched individuals. We then group
oers in bins corresponding to participants’ current payo. We normalize the number of oers
by the volume of oers made by the corresponding type across all rounds. Table 6 presents the
resulting fraction of oers by each type in each of our treatments, conditioning on the current pay
bin. Horizontal lines in the table correspond to a satisficing rule, allowing for a 20% mistake rate.
That is, payos exceeding those the line represents yield fewer than 20% of oers. As can be seen,
similar qualitative conclusions result from using lower mistake thresholds.
21
Table 6: Frequency of Oers Made Conditional on the Current Pay
Supermodular
Low Type Medium Type High Type
Current Pay Complete Incomplete Complete Incomplete Complete Incomplete
1 to 4 0.87 0.64 0.03 0.08 0.00 0.04
5 to 8 0.13 0.28 0.29 0.25 0.00 0.05
9 to 12 0.00 0.05 0.28 0.23 0.03 0.16
13 to 16 0.00 0.01 0.35 0.33 0.06 0.09
17 to 24 0.00 0.01 0.04 0.09 0.39 0.30
25 to 32 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.33 0.23
33 to 40 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.18 0.12
41 and above 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.01
Submodular
Low Type Medium Type High Type
Current Pay Complete Incomplete Complete Incomplete Complete Incomplete
1 to 4 0.33 0.26 0.00 0.06 0.00 0.00
5 to 8 0.17 0.24 0.00 0.12 0.00 0.00
9 to 12 0.13 0.11 0.03 0.10 0.00 0.01
13 to 16 0.27 0.24 0.27 0.17 0.01 0.01
17 to 24 0.11 0.11 0.60 0.37 0.05 0.18
25 to 32 0.00 0.04 0.11 0.17 0.37 0.53
33 to 40 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.51 0.23
41 and above 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.05 0.04
Notes: Fractions represent the frequency of oers of a particular type in a particular market conditional on current-
payo bin. The horizontal line corresponds to the satisficing thresholds with a 20% mistake threshold: payos beyond
the threshold lead to fewer than 20% of oers.
Estimated satisficing thresholds are remarkably consistent across complete- and incomplete-
information markets across types, with only one exception corresponding to low types in super-
modular markets. This consistency is reassuring and suggests that market positions are among the
strongest forces shaping our participants’ behavior. The next section explores this idea further.
21
Similar levels are derived when considering the first and second half of each market’s operations separately. In
addition, we do not see substantial dierences across early and later rounds. Oer rates documented in Table 6 nat-
urally reflect a combination of how active people are conditional on their current pay and how frequently they find
themselves with that pay.
25
Table 7: Impact of Number of Oers on Final Payos
Low Medium High
Complete
Supermodular 0.19 (0.09) 0.16 (0.08) 0.14 (0.09)
Submodular 0.21 (0.07) 0.18 (0.06) 0.11 (0.11)
Incomplete
Supermodular 0.25 (0.10) 0.17 (0.08) 0.10 (0.05)
Submodular 0.22 (0.08) 0.17 (0.09) 0.11 (0.07)
(a) Fraction of Oers by Type
β
low
β
med
β
high
β
low
= β
med
β
low
= β
high
β
med
= β
high
R
2
(n)
Complete -0.17 -1.77 13.33 0.35 0.12 0.11 0.94 (480)
Supermodular (0.61) (1.74) (6.60)
Complete 1.05 1.18 -2.05 0.98 0.69 0.39 0.84 (480)
Submodular (4.70) (2.53) (5.04)
Incomplete -1.44 -10.64
-5.72 0.04 0.45 0.44 0.93 (480)
Supermodular (1.05) (3.76) (5.37)
Incomplete -17.72 -14.30
-9.96 0.79 0.41 0.63 0.74 (480)
Submodular (11.11) (4.81) (4.43)
(b) Payo Regressions
Notes: Panel (a) reports the average number of oers made by each participant type as a fraction of all oers made
in that specific market, with standard deviations in parentheses. Rows add up to 50%, modulo rounding. Panel (b)
reports the estimated coecients from linear regressions in which the dependent variable is the participants’ payo
and the independent variables include the constant, the dummies for medium and high types (leaving the low types
as the base group), the round and the round squared, two measures of altruism per participant, two measures of risk
attitudes per participant, and the fractions of oers extended by low, medium, and high types. The first three columns
in panel (b) report the estimated coecients, and robust standard errors in parentheses, on the fraction of oers made
by low, medium, and high types, respectively. Standard errors are clustered at the session level. The next three columns
report p-value tests of coecients based on these regressions. The final column reports the number of observations and
the R-squared.
5.3.3 Bargaining Styles
We now turn to the various bargaining styles participants used and how they aect outcomes in
our markets. The main message is that, while individuals vary widely in how they approach our
markets, in terms of the number of oers they make, their insistence on higher shares, etc., their
payos are not strongly aected by these diering interaction styles. By and large, payos are
determined by the governing match surpluses: supermodular or submodular, and the position
one takes in the market in terms of types.
26
We focus our discussion on one aspect of behavior: the number of oers made in a market. In
the Appendix, we include analogous analyses relating to other aspects: number of matches made
throughout the market, the share of surpluses demanded in oers, and which quintile the first
and last matches were created. The messages from these are qualitatively identical.
Panel (a) of Table 7 illustrates, for each of our treatments, the fraction of oers made by type,
as well as their standard deviation.
22
There is substantial variation in the number of oers partic-
ipants make, reflected in the relatively large standard deviations. While there are some notable
dierences across types, with lower types generally making more oers than higher types, dier-
ences across information or preference treatments are insignificant.
Panel (b) of Table 7 illustrates the impacts of the number of oers on payos. In the reported
regressions, we explain the final payo of a participant by their position, market characteristics,
and the number of oers they make, allowing for fixed-eects by participant and clustering errors
at the session level. The association is insignificant in all but one case, pertaining to medium types
in the incomplete-information supermodular markets, where we observe a moderately positive
association between fraction of oers made and final payo.
A similar picture emerges when considering variations at the individual level. We consider
participants who are “high earners,” receiving a final payo that is above the average payo for
the role they take in at least 7 of the 10 rounds played. Analogously, we consider “low earners”
as those receiving a final payo below the average for their role in at least 7 of the 10 rounds.
“Medium earners” are all those that remain. The distribution of the various types of earners is
similar to that which would be generated by random choice, with somewhat more “high earn-
ers.
23
We see minute dierences between the three categories of earners in terms of fraction
of oers made, when controlling for market features, position in the market, session round, and
overall number of oers made in the market (see the Appendix for detailed regression results).
Figure 4 summarizes this discussion. For each of our treatments, and each market position,
or type, we classify participants according to the fraction of oers they made, divided into 9
categories. We see a substantial number of observations in each of these categories, particularly
22
Since there are 6 participants in each market, if all made oers at equal volumes, we would expect each to make
16.66% of the oers observed.
23
For example, were payos determined at random, we would expect 17.19% of participants to be classified as
“high earners. In our data, we see 27.08%, 35.42%, 31.25%, and 22.92% high earners in the complete supermodular,
incomplete supermodular, complete submodular, and incomplete submodular treatments, respectively.
27
Figure 4: Payos by Type as a Function of Fraction of Oers Made
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
< 0.05 0.05 -
0.10
0.10 -
0.15
0.15 -
0.20
0.20 -
0.25
0.25 -
0.30
0.30 -
0.35
0.35 -
0.40
>0.40
Incomplete Submodular
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
< 0.05 0.05 -
0.10
0.10 -
0.15
0.15 -
0.20
0.20 -
0.25
0.25 -
0.30
0.30 -
0.35
0.35 -
0.40
>0.40
Incomplete Supermodular
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
< 0.05 0.05 -
0.10
0.10 -
0.15
0.15 -
0.20
0.20 -
0.25
0.25 -
0.30
0.30 -
0.35
0.35 -
0.40
>0.40
Complete Supermodular
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
< 0.05 0.05 -
0.10
0.10 -
0.15
0.15 -
0.20
0.20 -
0.25
0.25 -
0.30
0.30 -
0.35
0.35 -
0.40
>0.40
Complete Submodular
High type Medium type
Low type
Notes: The height of white bars represents the average payo of low-type participants in a particular market for a
given fraction of market oers they make. Similarly, the heights of the orange and grey bars represent average payos
of medium- and high-type players, respectively, conditional on the fraction of oers they make in a market.
for those pertaining to fewer than 0.25 of market oers (see Table A.3 in Appendix A). However,
as the figure illustrates, we see little impact of this volume of oers on average payos for any of
the types.
These results are interesting in view of the vast literature suggesting that bargaining strategies
may be important in various contexts, most notably in labor markets; see Bertrand (2011) and
Shell (2006). While our settings are certainly simplistic in many ways, they suggest a very dierent
story. Market position appears to have a dominant impact on outcomes. Who one matches with,
and with what transfer, depends importantly on the role one occupies in the market, while being
relatively insensitive to how one bargains.
28
6 Conclusions
We report an array of results examining outcomes and the dynamics of interactions in decentral-
ized matching markets. We allow for transfers and consider markets with complete and incom-
plete information, and with supermodular or submodular surplus structures.
Without transfers, prior literature has suggested that decentralized interactions often culmi-
nate in stable, and hence ecient, outcomes. Our first main message is that, in the presence
of transfers, a substantial fraction of outcomes is still ecient, while fewer outcomes are stable.
Participants often establish the matches required for eciency, but find it more dicult to settle
on transfers that induce stable outcomes. Our second message is that limited information and
the shift from a supermodular to a submodular surplus structure have important impacts. Lim-
ited information constitutes an important hurdle for stability, even when participants have ample
opportunities to learn about others through market interactions. Stability is similarly more chal-
lenging to achieve with submodular surpluses. Together, incomplete information and submodu-
larity are deadly for stability—in those markets, less than 5% of ultimate outcomes are stable. Our
third message pertains to the dynamics of interactions. When surpluses are supermodular, high
types tend to match first, followed by medium types, and then by low types. When surpluses are
submodular, there is substantial variation in the order of match formation and resulting payos.
Indeed, the ultimate payo distribution is nearly uniform. Participants’ behavior is consistent
with a satisficing heuristic in which payo targets are type dependent. The final message emerg-
ing from our data regards bargaining styles. While we see variation in bargaining patterns across
individuals, those seem to have little impact on final payos. The main determinants of partici-
pants’ payos in our markets are the governing surplus structure and their positions, or types.
We believe our study opens the door for several further investigations, both theoretical and
experimental. As described in our literature review, several recent papers have suggested some
natural stability notions allowing for incomplete information on one side. The results from those
papers cannot be easily reconciled with our data. In part, this may be due to the fact that the
suggested notions are agnostic about the decentralized process that takes place in the market.
In particular, these solution concepts typically take as fixed a specification of uncertainty and
a candidate stable outcome, ignoring the fact that the residual uncertainty is likely to depend
on the process by which the candidate outcome is attained. We hope our experimental results
29
might be useful in refining those stability notions to richer settings. Our results point to the need
for a model allowing agents to glean complete information about the other side of the market
through the matching process, while settling on an outcome that is not complete-information
stable. Our experiments also suggest that, when information is incomplete, there might be great
value for centralization if (complete-information) stability is an objective. Nonetheless, the extant
literature oers little insights on the design of matching markets in the presence of incomplete
information, for any objective. We believe this would be a fruitful direction for future research.
Our experiments examine bargaining frictions due to transfers and incomplete information.
There are certainly other frictions that would be interesting to inspect. In applications, oers are
often costly—in labor markets, employers frequently have limited interview slots or limited oers
to make, regardless of their yield; in marriage markets, dating is costly in terms of both time and
money. Naturally, frictions pertaining to oer costs may dampen market activity. That, in turn,
would limit learning even further, as participants “try out” fewer matches. The ineciencies we
identify may then oer lower bounds on the ineciencies one might expect in practice. There are
other details that our basic design does not incorporate: whether oers are exploding, commu-
nication channels between market participants, etc. We hope our study sets the stage for further
investigations of such additional frictions.
References
Agranov, M. and M. Elliott (2021): “Commitment and (in)Eciency: A Bargaining Experi-
ment,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 19, 790–838.
Alston, M. (2020): “On the Non-existence of Stable Matches with Incomplete Information,”
Games and Economic Behavior, 120, 336–344.
Andreoni, J. and B. D. Bernheim (2009): “Social Image and the 50–50 Norm: A Theoretical and
Experimental Analysis of Audience Eects,” Econometrica, 77, 1607–1636.
Becker, G. S. (1973): A Theory of Marriage: Part I,” Journal of Political Economy, 81, 813–846.
Bertrand, M. (2011): “New Perspectives on Gender,” in Handbook of Labor Economics, vol 4b, ed.
by O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1543–1590.
30
Bikhchandani, S. (2017): “Stability with One-sided Incomplete Information,” Journal of Economic
Theory, 168, 372–399.
Caplin, A., M. Dean, and D. Martin (2011): “Search and Satisficing,” American Economic Review,
101, 2899–2922.
Chade, H., J. Eeckhout, and L. Smith (2017): “Sorting through search and matching models in
economics,” Journal of Economic Literature, 55, 493–544.
Chen, D. L., M. Schonger, and C. Wickens (2016): “oTree—An Open-source Platform for Labo-
ratory, Online, and Field Experiments,” Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 9, 88–97.
Chen, Y. and T. Sönmez (2006): “School Choice: An Experimental Study,” Journal of Economic
theory, 127, 202–231.
Chen, Y.-C. and G. Hu (2020): “Learning by Matching,” Theoretical Economics, 15, 29–56.
Chiappori, P.-A. (2017): Matching with Transfers: The Economics of Love and Marriage, Princeton
University Press.
Echenique, F. and L. Yariv (2013): An Experimental Study of Decentralized Matching,” .
Ferdowsian, A., M. Niederle, and L. Yariv (2022): “Decentralized Matching with Aligned Pref-
erences,” .
Gneezy, U. and J. Potters (1997): An Experiment on Risk Taking and Evaluation Periods,” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 631–645.
Hakimov, R. and D. Kübler (2021): “Experiments on centralized school choice and college admis-
sions: A Survey,” Experimental Economics, 24, 434–488.
He, S., J. Wu, and H. Zhang (2022): “Decentralized Matching with Transfers: Experimental and
Noncooperative Analyses,” .
Kapor, A. J., C. A. Neilson, and S. D. Zimmerman (2020): “Heterogeneous Beliefs and School
Choice Mechanisms,” American Economic Review, 110, 1274–1315.
Liu, Q. (2022): “Stability and Bayesian Consistency in Two-Sided Markets,” American Economic
Review, 110, 2625–2666.
31
Liu, Q., G. J. Mailath, A. Postlewaite, and L. Samuelson (2014): “Stable Matching with Incom-
plete Information,” Econometrica, 82, 541–587.
Nalbantian, H. R. and A. Schotter (1995): “Matching and Eciency in the Baseball Free-Agent
System: An Experimental Examination,” Journal of Labor Economics, 13, 1–31.
Niederle, M. and A. E. Roth (2009): “Market Culture: How Rules Governing Exploding Oers
Aect Market Performance,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 1, 199–219.
Pais, J. and Á. Pintér (2008): “School Choice and Information: An Experimental Study on Match-
ing Mechanisms,” Games and Economic Behavior, 64, 303–328.
Pais, J., Á. Pintér, and R. F. Veszteg (2020): “Decentralized Matching Markets with(out) Frictions:
A Laboratory Experiment,” Experimental Economics, 23, 212–239.
Plott, C., N. Roy, and B. Tong (2013): “Marshall and Walras, Disequilibrium Trades and the
Dynamics of Equilibration in the Continuous Double Auction Market,” Journal of Economic Be-
havior and Organization, 94, 109–205.
Roth, A. E. and M. Sotomayor (1990): “Two-Sided Matching: A Study in Game-theoretic Model-
ing and Analysis,” Econometric Society Monographs, 18.
Roth, A. E. and J. H. V. Vate (1990): “Random paths to stability in two-sided matching,” Econo-
metrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 1475–1480.
Shell, G. R. (2006): Bargaining for Advantage: Negotiation Strategies for Reasonable People, Penguin.
32
A Additional Analysis
A.1 Do Markets Start the Same Way?
Since most of our results consider the entirety of participants’ market interactions, one may won-
der whether the impact of the surplus variety occurs through market dynamics alone. In this
section, we show that even initial activity varies by the sort of surplus that governs preferences.
We focus on complete-information markets, since initial interactions in incomplete-information
markets are naturally noisy due to the limited knowledge participants have regarding their own
and others’ preferences.
Figure A.1 illustrates the frequency of matches formed and oers made at the start of our
markets. As can be seen, dierent patterns emerge across our markets. For example, in our
supermodular markets, initial matches are mostly formed between stable partners, with a pre-
dominance of matches and oers between high types. In contrast, in our submodular markets,
while early matches between high types are still prevalent, most oers occur between low and
high types, or between medium and high types. Furthermore, there is roughly an equal share of
matches between low and high, medium and high, or two medium types.
Table A.2 suggests that the profile of transfers also diers across market classes from the start.
Interestingly, submodular markets are characterized by more equal splits at the start of interac-
tions, even though, as we showed in the paper, this pattern reverses as markets evolve.
Table A.2: Frequency of Equal Splits in First Deals/Oers
First two deals First two oers
Supermodular Submodular Supermodular Submodular
LL 0.78 1.00 0.00
LM 0.71 1.00 0.64 0.50
LH 0.29 0.20 0.55 0.42
MM 0.83 0.95 0.77 0.75
MH 0.47 0.60 0.59 0.70
HH 0.75 0.89 0.67 0.79
Notes: Equal split corresponds to between 45% and 55% of the total surplus.
A.2 Bargaining Styles
Table A.3 below is the companion table for Figure 4 in the main text of the paper. It depicts the
number of observations we have for each of the categories representing the fraction of oers made
33
Figure A.1: First Two Oers and Deals with Complete Information
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
35%
Supermodular Submodular Supermodular Submodular
First two deals First two offers
How do Complete Info markets start?
LL LM LH MM MH HH
Note: Numbers for LM, LH, and ML are divided by two because there are twice as many opportunities to
make these deals in the markets than the congruent one like LL, MM, and HH.
Notes: The frequencies for non-congruent matches (LM, LH, MH) are divided by two, since there are twice as many
opportunities to make such oers/deals than congruent ones (LL, MM, and HH).
in a market by a particular player type in a particular market variety. There are 160 observations
for each player type in each market (8 groups × 10 markets × 2 players of each type).
Next, we replicate the analysis presented in the main body of the paper regarding bargain-
ing styles of market participants with respect to other characteristics of market behavior such as
number of matches made throughout the market, the share of surpluses demanded when making
oers, and the timing in which the first and last matches were created. For each of these four
characteristics, we present the variation across dierent types of players and the eects of this
variation on final payos (using regression analysis similar to that reported in Table 6).
In Table A.6 we report tests pertaining to comparisons of coecients based on regression anal-
ysis of the bargaining style of “high earners.” Specifically, for each market structure, correspond-
ing to the governing surplus and information available, we run a linear regression in which the
dependent variable is one of the market behavior characteristics—number of oers, number of
deals, share of surplus requested in oers, and timing of the first and last match—on a constant,
indicators for medium- and high-type participants, interaction terms corresponding to high earn-
ings and type, and control variables. The controls include the round number, the fixed eects
34
Table A.3: Number of observations for each category in Figure 4
Complete Supermodular Complete Submodular
low medium high low medium high
less than 0.05 21 28 39 6 13 41
0.05 - 0.10 30 33 26 15 20 45
0.10 - 0.15 21 23 28 35 33 31
0.15 - 0.20 19 24 22 23 25 15
0.20 - 0.25 18 11 19 19 33 12
0.25 - 0.30 15 16 8 30 12 9
0.30 - 0.35 16 12 7 14 12 4
0.35 - 0.40 7 6 5 7 7 1
more than 0.40 13 7 6 11 5 2
Incomplete Supermodular Incomplete Submodular
low medium high low medium high
less than 0.05 4 14 46 2 17 51
0.05 - 0.10 9 30 50 15 33 47
0.10 - 0.15 23 37 33 32 30 22
0.15 - 0.20 24 23 19 23 21 18
0.20 - 0.25 30 22 2 26 23 9
0.25 - 0.30 26 15 17 26 19 8
0.30 - 0.35 23 6 2 15 7 2
0.35 - 0.40 7 6 1 8 5 1
more than 0.40 14 7 0 13 5 2
Notes: We present the number of observations per category; there are 160 observations per market and type.
for individual participants, the total number of oers made in the market in the first set of re-
gressions, and the total number of deals made in the market in the second set of regressions. We
cluster standard errors at the session level to account for interdependencies of observations that
come from the same session. We report the estimated coecients and the robust standard errors
in parentheses for the interaction terms of high earners with their type and test whether those in-
teraction coecients are significantly dierent from zero. If they are, this means that high earners
of the specified type behave in a systematically dierent way than low earners.
35
Table A.4: Variation in Market Behavior
Number of Matches by Type (frac) Share of Surplus in Oers (out of 100%)
Low Medium High Low Medium High
Complete
Supermodular 0.31 (0.06) 0.36 (0.06) 0.33 (0.06) 49.15 (6.58) 49.31 (6.36) 55.20 (4.79)
Submodular 0.24 (0.06) 0.34 (0.06) 0.40 (0.08) 40.53 (6.56) 48.85 (4.22) 58.67 (8.07)
Incomplete
Supermodular 0.38 (0.08) 0.37 (0.06) 0.25 (0.08) 47.45 (7.31) 49.68 (7.00) 52.63 (7.86)
Submodular 0.33 (0.06) 0.32 (0.07) 0.34 (0.09) 43.59 (7.49) 50.85 (6.69) 55.36 (5.95)
First Match (quintile) Last Match (quintile)
Low Medium High Low Medium High
Complete
Supermodular 3.02 (1.09) 1.98 (0.71) 1.88 (0.77) 4.00 (0.89) 3.58 (0.98) 3.15 (1.02)
Submodular 2.40 (0.99) 1.82 (0.77) 1.39 (0.48) 3.93 (0.86) 4.06 (0.73) 3.72 (0.70)
Incomplete
Supermodular 1.09 (0.15) 1.08 (0.14) 1.05 (0.11) 4.47 (0.70) 4.00 (0.91) 2.57 (0.88)
Submodular 1.13 (0.24) 1.08 (0.19) 1.05 (0.12) 4.24 (0.70) 3.95 (0.85) 3.65 (0.97)
36
Table A.5: Does Market Behavior Aects Final Payos? Regression Analysis
β
low
β
med
β
high
β
low
= β
med
β
low
= β
high
β
med
= β
high
R
2
(n)
Complete
Supermodular 0.82 (1.22) -2.53 (1.31) 20.10 (17.51) 0.18 0.32 0.30 0.94 (480)
Submodular -3.67 (3.04) -6.04
(2.44) 2.70 (1.79) 0.35 0.26 0.08 0.84 (480)
Incomplete
Supermodular 2.20 (2.19) -9.13
(3.28) -9.30
∗∗
(2.34) 0.08 0.03 0.97 0.91 (480)
Submodular -11.63 (6.59) -8.66
∗∗
(2.12) 1.44 (5.22) 0.73 0.01 0.23 0.68 (480)
(a) Number of Matches by Type
β
low
β
med
β
high
β
low
= β
med
β
low
= β
high
β
med
= β
high
R
2
(n)
Complete
Supermodular 0.01 (0.01) 0.01 (0.02) 0.02 (0.02) 0.83 0.57 0.61 0.92 (428)
Submodular -0.02 (0.07) -0.04 (0.02) -0.01 (0.05) 0.81 0.81 0.37 0.83 (448)
Incomplete
Supermodular 0.003 (0.01) 0.10 (0.05) 0.04 (0.04) 0.19 0.48 0.22 0.91 (397)
Submodular 0.05 (0.04) -0.04 (0.09) 0.14 (0.08) 0.46 0.52 0.05 0.69 (427)
(b) Share of Surplus in Oers
β
low
β
med
β
high
β
low
= β
med
β
low
= β
high
β
med
= β
high
R
2
(n)
Complete
Supermodular -0.04 (0.03) 0.17 (0.11) -0.03 (0.08) 0.23 0.86 0.14 0.96 (478)
Submodular -0.29 (0.15) 0.21 (0.14) 0.43 (0.51) 0.02 0.29 0.71 0.84 (480)
Incomplete
Supermodular -0.38 (0.55) 0.84
∗∗
(0.16) 0.54
(0.16) 0.12 0.23 0.26 0.91 (480)
Submodular -0.26 (0.97) 0.99 (1.91) -0.65 (1.28) 0.30 0.50 0.15 0.68 (480)
(c) Timing of First Match (quintile)
β
low
β
med
β
high
β
low
= β
med
β
low
= β
high
β
med
= β
high
R
2
(n)
Complete
Supermodular 0.006 (0.03) -0.01 (0.13) 0.30 (0.17) 0.92 0.21 0.09 0.96 (466)
Submodular -0.37 (0.28) -0.19 (0.23) 0.11 (0.36) 0.42 0.51 0.61 0.84 (476)
Incomplete
Supermodular 0.16 (0.17) -0.26 (0.24) -0.47 (0.16) 0.38 0.00 0.61 0.91 (480)
Submodular -0.85 (0.74) -0.83 (0.30) 0.43 (0.28) 0.98 0.19 0.10 0.68 (480)
(d) Timing of Last Match (quintile)
Notes: Each row corresponds to one regression. The dependent variable is the final payo of a player. The independent
variables contain a constant, the dummies for medium- and high-type players, interaction between the relevant charac-
teristics of market behavior (number of deals, share of surplus, timing of the first and the last match) and player type,
as well as individual controls for risk attitudes and degree of altruism as captured by the auxiliary tasks conducted at
the end of the experiment. We cluster the standard errors by session. The number of observations in the panel (b) is
smaller than in other panels because some participants never made an oer in a particular market.
37
Table A.6: Individual Analysis of Bargaining Styles and Its Eect on Payos
Number of Oers Number of Deals
Low Medium High Low Medium High
Complete
Supermodular 0.05
∗∗
(0.01) 0.003 (0.01) 0.0001 (0.01) -0.003 (0.02) -0.02
∗∗
(0.006) -0.01 (0.02)
Submodular 0.07
(0.03) 0.02
∗∗
(0.006) 0.02 (0.02) 0.02 (0.02) 0.01 (0.02) 0.03 (0.02)
Incomplete
Supermodular 0.11
∗∗
(0.02) 0.10
∗∗
(0.01) 0.11
∗∗
(0.01) -0.10
∗∗
(0.03) -0.08
∗∗
(0.009) -0.04 (0.02)
Submodular 0.18
∗∗
(0.02) 0.14
∗∗
(0.03) 0.19
∗∗
(0.03) 0.01 (0.03) -0.02 (0.04) -0.00004 (0.0002)
Share of Surplus in Oers
Low Medium High
Complete
Supermodular 3.77
∗∗
(0.66) 4.47
∗∗
(1.18) 1.97
(0.75)
Submodular 3.84 (2.45) 5.74
∗∗
(1.57) 5.11
∗∗
(1.17)
Incomplete
Supermodular 1.29 (1.97) 1.31 (0.61) 0.48 (1.32)
Submodular -7.17
∗∗
(1.64) -7.80
∗∗
(1.89) -3.22
∗∗
(0.76)
Timing of First Deal (in quintiles) Timing of Last Deal (in quintiles)
Low Medium High Low Medium High
Complete
Supermodular 0.31 (0.25) -0.09 (0.11) -0.30 (0.22) 0.58
∗∗
(0.12) -0.12 (0.09) -0.08 (0.12)
Submodular -1.34
∗∗
(0.12) -1.28
∗∗
(0.20) -1.37
∗∗
(0.18) -0.04 (0.06) -0.39 (0.18) -0.20 (0.14)
Incomplete
Supermodular -0.11 (0.06) -0.10
∗∗
(0.01) -0.09
(0.04) -0.48 (0.36) -0.69
∗∗
(0.16) -0.19 (0.11)
Submodular 0.05 (0.03) 0.12
∗∗
(0.02) 0.11
∗∗
(0.02) 0.42 (0.34) 0.27 (0.20) 1.00
∗∗
(0.16)
Notes: see description above
38
B Predictions from Stability with Transfers
As described in Section 3, a stable outcome is an individually rational outcome that has no block-
ing pairs. When transfers are available, there exist many transfer profiles that sustain stable
outcomes in both our supermodular and submodular markets. The associated stable matching,
however, is unique for both market types. The table below shows the system of inequalities for
each market type that identifies the set of stable transfer profiles. We use x
i
to denote the payo
of market participant i, using the labels in Table 1 in the main text. The first column corresponds
to our supermodular market, the second to our submodular market.
Supermodular market Submodular market
x
Kiwi
0 x
Kiwi
0
x
Mango
0 x
Mango
0
x
Plum
0 x
Plum
0
x
Blue
0 x
Blue
0
x
Crimson
0 x
Crimson
0
x
White
0 x
White
0
x
Kiwi
+ x
Blue
8 x
Kiwi
+ x
Blue
8
x
Kiwi
+ x
Crimson
16 x
Kiwi
+ x
Crimson
32
x
Kiwi
+ x
White
24 x
Kiwi
+ x
White
56
x
Mango
+ x
Blue
16 x
Mango
+ x
Blue
32
x
Mango
+ x
Crimson
32 x
Mango
+ x
Crimson
48
x
Mango
+ x
White
48 x
Mango
+ x
White
64
x
Plum
+ x
Blue
24 x
Plum
+ x
Blue
56
x
Plum
+ x
Crimson
48 x
Plum
+ x
Crimson
64
x
Plum
+ x
White
72 x
Plum
+ x
White
72
x
Kiwi
+ x
Mango
+ x
Plum
+ x
Kiwi
+ x
Mango
+ x
Plum
+
+x
Blue
+ x
Crimson
+ x
White
112 +x
Blue
+ x
Crimson
+ x
White
160
39
C ONLINE APPENDIX: Sample Instructions
Welcome. Welcome to EBEL and thank you for participating in today’s experiment. Please place
all of your personal belongings away so that we can have your complete attention. Please use the
laptops as instructed. In particular, please do not attempt to browse the web or use programs
unrelated to the experiment.
Guidelines. You will be paid in private and in cash at the end of the experiment. The amount
that you ultimately earn in the experiment depends on your decisions, the decisions of others, and
random chance. You have each earned a $10 payment for showing up on time. You will be using
laptops for the entire experiment, and all interactions between yourself and others will take place
via the laptop?s terminal. Please DO NOT socialize or talk.
Overview. Today’s experiment is about matching. The main part of the experiment consists
of 11 rounds: one practice round and 10 actual rounds. We will also ask you to complete several
simple tasks at the end.
At the beginning of the experiment, you will be randomly assigned a role: either a color or a
food. Your role will remain fixed across all rounds of the experiment. At the beginning of each
round, you will be randomly assigned a type:
If you are a color, you can be one of three types: Blue, Crimson, or White.
If you are a food, you can be one of three types: Kiwi, Mango, or Plum.
Your type (but not your role) may change across each round of the experiment.
In each round, you will be randomly assigned to a group of six: three colors (one Blue, one
Crimson, and one White) and three foods (one Kiwi, one Mango, and one Plum). Your goal in
each round is to match with an individual from the opposite role. If you are a color, your goal is
to match with a food. If you are a food, your goal is to match with a color.
Match Payo.
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 8 16 24
CRIMSON 16 32 48
WHITE 24 48 72
40
A color and food who match together earn a match payo (in tokens). You will earn a dierent
payo depending on whom you match with and how you choose to split the match payo.
Example 1:
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 8 16 24
CRIMSON 16 32 48
WHITE 24 48 72
Blue and Mango can match together, with the sum of payos for Blue and Mango yielding 16
tokens. For example, Blue could receive a payo of 10 tokens and Mango would then receive a
payo of 6 tokens. Another example: Blue could receive a payo of 7 tokens and Mango would
then receive a payo of 9 tokens.
Example 2:
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 8 16 24
CRIMSON 16 32 48
WHITE 24 48 72
Crimson and Plum can match together, with the sum of payos for Crimson and Plum yield-
ing 48 tokens. For example, Crimson could receive a payo of 30 tokens and Plum would then
receive a payo of 18 tokens. Another example: Crimson could receive a payo of 23 tokens and
Plum would then receive a payo of 25 tokens.
Example 3:
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 8 16 24
CRIMSON 16 32 48
WHITE 24 48 72
White and Kiwi can match together, with the sum of payos for White and Kiwi yielding 24
tokens. For example, White could receive a payo of 18 tokens and Kiwi would then receive a
payo of 6 tokens. Another example: White could receive a payo of 9 tokens and Kiwi would
then receive a payo of 15 tokens.
41
Information about the payo matrix. At the beginning of each round, we will reshue the
rows and columns of the matrix.
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 8 16 24
CRIMSON 16 32 48
WHITE 24 48 72
Examples:
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 8 16 24
CRIMSON 16 32 48
WHITE 24 48 72
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 16 32 48
CRIMSON 24 48 72
WHITE 8 16 24
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 24 16 8
CRIMSON 48 32 16
WHITE 72 48 24
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 48 32 16
CRIMSON 72 48 24
WHITE 24 16 8
All possible reshuings are equally likely. At the beginning of each round, you will not know
how the matrix was reshued, but you will know which payos you might receive.
Examples. Suppose you are Blue, and you learn that your payos might be 16, 32, 48. It might
be that a match with Kiwi generates 16, a match with Mango generates 32, and a match with Plum
generates 48.
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 16 32 48
CRIMSON 24 48 72
WHITE 8 16 24
It might be that a match with Kiwi generates 48, a match with Mango generates 32, and a
match with Plum generates 16.
KIWI MANGO PLUM
BLUE 48 32 16
CRIMSON 72 48 24
WHITE 24 16 8
All possible reshuings are equally likely. While you will know your possible payos, you
will not know which payo corresponds to which matching. Your payos will appear on the top
42
part of your interface. Note that no other subject in your group observes your possible match
payos. Each person only sees his or her own possible match payos.
Rules of the Experiment. In each round, you will start o unmatched. You are free to make
at most one match proposal to any individual of the opposite role at any given time.
A match proposal must specify what your partner will get. If your proposal is accepted, then
you will get the match payo minus what your partner will get. You are also free to accept or
reject match proposals that you receive from other individuals. Any match proposal that is not
accepted or rejected within 10 seconds will automatically disappear. When a match is accepted,
both the proposer and the receiver see the payos they get from the match.
Example 1: Suppose you are Blue, and you know your possible match payos are 16, 32, and
48. If you make an oer of 10 to Kiwi, which gets accepted, you might see that you get 6 and Kiwi
gets 10. This implies that you and Kiwi have a match payo of 6+10 = 16.
Example 2: Suppose you are Blue, and you know your possible match payos are 16, 32, and
48. If you make an oer of 10 to Kiwi, which gets accepted, you might see that you get 38 and
Kiwi gets 10. This implies that you and Kiwi have a match payo of 38+10 = 48.
Click on the square to
make an offer
Move slider to suggest
the responder’s payoff
Your possible match
payoffs
Click on the square to
make an offer
Move slider to suggest
the responder’s payoff
Your possible match
payoffs
43
Confirmation of offer
44
Decision to accept
or reject
Timer
45
When your offer
is accepted, you
see the payoffs
46
When you accept
an offer, you
see the payoffs
47
Current match
entries are
shaded in orange
48
Rules of the Experiment, cont... If you proposed a match which was accepted and in which
your own earnings are negative, then you will have an opportunity to unilaterally break this match
by clicking a “cancel” button.
Negative payoff
Click Cancel button to
cancel this match
If you are currently matched, you can still make a match proposal to another individual. If the
match proposal is accepted, then your current match will be broken. If you are currently matched,
you can still receive match proposals from other individuals. If you accept a match proposal, then
your current match will be broken. When you accept a match, or someone else accepts a match
with you, any proposal you had made or received before will be automatically rejected.
49
You can make an
offer while matched
50
Confirmation of
offer while matched
Confirmation of
offer while matched
51
A round ends after 30 seconds of inactivity (i.e., after 30 seconds in which no new match
proposals have been made). Whenever you are ready to proceed, you can also press the “Move on
to Next Round” button. When at least 5 in your group press the button, you will automatically
move to the next round (without waiting the 30 seconds). If any activity occurs after you press
the button, the button will get released.
Press whenever
ready to proceed
to next round
52
Payos for a Round. Your payo when the round ends is your final payo for that round. If
you are not matched at the end of the round, your final payo for that round is 0. Your payo
from temporary matches that are made and then broken during a round do not count for your
final payo.
Timer for the round
(round ends after
30 seconds of
inactivity)
Post-Experiment. At the end of the experiment, you will be paid the sum of your payos
across rounds (excluding the practice round). You will also be asked to complete several simple
tasks at the end. You can earn additional money based on your decisions in these tasks.
Your Earnings. Your total earnings in the experiment are the sum of the following amounts:
$10 show-up payment
payo from 10 main rounds: 10 tokens = 1 dollar
payo from the simple tasks:
53
You need not tell any other participant how much you earned. If there are no questions, we
will now begin the actual experiment.
54